The following is the English version of an interview with Thomas Storck by Martin Bürger of Catholic News Agency, Germany, published with the title, Distributismus: Die bessere Alternative zu Kapitalismus und Sozialismus? Ein Gespräch mit Thomas Storck
Bürger: What
exactly is distributism? How is it defined?
Storck: Probably the best definition of distributism is that
offered by G. K. Chesterton’s younger brother, Cecil, in 1917.
“A Distributist is a man who desires that the means of production should, generally speaking, remain private property, but that their ownership should be so distributed that the determining mass offamilies—ideally every family—should have an efficient share therein. That is Distributism, and nothing else is Distributism … Distributism is quite as possible in an industrial or commercial as in an agrarian community …”
Note that
distributism does not require an agrarian society, but is equally
applicable to “an industrial or commercial” society.
It is also important
to note that private ownership of the means of production does not
necessarily mean individual ownership. While small businesses,
indeed micro-businesses, are a key part of a distributist economy, we
recognize that not all enterprises can be carried on in this way. For
necessarily larger enterprises, we support worker-owned cooperatives,
such as the very successful Mondragon cooperatives in Spain. The
Australian distributist, Race Mathews, in his book, Jobs of Our
Own, calls this “evolved distributism.” In Europe, the United
States and elsewhere, employee-owned companies are not uncommon, and
have been successful in various fields, including manufacturing,
shipping and retail.
Bürger: What
characterizes a distributist society? You already indicated that it’s
not necessarily agrarian …
Storck:
Indeed, distributism by no means requires an agrarian society, nor a
low level of technology. Aside from the formal note of
distributism—well-distributed private property—a distributist
society and economy would try to subordinate economic activity to the
common good and to the fullness of human life. Thus a distributist
society would tend to strive not for unlimited riches but a plentiful
sufficiency, so that men could devote their efforts to the more
important things, the things of God, of the family, of friendship, of
the intellect and the arts.
Bürger:
What is the distributist position on interest?
Storck: It’s
not the distributist position but rather the Catholic position. The
Church has never retracted its teaching that interest charged solely
on account of a loan is usury and ipso facto unjust. The
Church also recognizes, however, that often there are other reasons
that interest may justly be charged, what are called extrinsic
titles, and this kind of interest is not usury. I argued this point
at length a few years ago in an article
in the theological journal, Communio. A shorter version of
the article is available here.
Bürger:
Capitalism has been tried (and found very successful), socialism has
been tried (and found unlivable).
Storck: I
think we have to be careful when we speak about capitalism.
Capitalism varies considerably worldwide. Capitalism in Germany, with
its co-determination, is not the same as capitalism in the United
States, which approaches more closely to an economy ruled by “a
free competition of forces” which Pius XI condemned and called “a
poisoned spring” (Quadragesimo Anno, no. 88). Indeed, in
most European countries there have been strong countervailing forces,
both political and cultural, which moderate the tendencies of
capitalism toward materialism and exploitation. And capitalism in
China or in Bangladesh operates differently still.
Bürger:
How do you define capitalism?
Storck:
Economists and economic historians are not in agreement as to what
exactly capitalism is. Pope Pius XI characterized capitalism in
Quadragesimo Anno, no. 100, as the separation of ownership and
work, as “that economic system in which were provided by different
people the capital and labor jointly needed for production,” and I
consider this the best definition. You’ll note that by separating
ownership from work, a class of people is created, the owners, who
are one step removed from the actual productive process, and thus
tend to regard not production for use, but the sale of any product,
useful or not, as the purpose of economic activity. Secondly, by
creating the labor market divide—owners versus their
employees—workers are always a cost item for capitalist owners, and
hence the tendency to drive down wages, which historically has marked
capitalism. It was only with effective labor organizations, as well
as government regulation, that the worst features of capitalism were
done away with or minimized. Because of co-determination, capitalism
in Germany does not have most of the bad features of capitalism, but
this is because of legal and cultural norms that work against the
main point of capitalism, its separation of ownership and work. The
participation of workers in managing companies mitigates that
separation, and the mandatory wage agreements likewise mitigate the
tendency of capitalism to regard workers as simply a cost item to be
procured as cheaply as possible.
In addition, in
Germany the hostility between management or ownership and labor,
which has characterized capitalism elsewhere, including the United
States, is minimized by cultural norms which promote a sense of
partnership and cooperation between management and labor.
Where capitalism is
not restrained by something like co-determination, I would hardly
call it a success. It has certainly
been successful in the production of great quantities of stuff,
sometimes useful, sometimes not. It has also been a chief factor in
the commercialization of society, which can be seen clearly in the
US, where everything is valued in terms of its monetary worth, for
instance, higher education is justified almost exclusively because of
the higher salaries which graduates usually obtain. Capitalism has also
done great damage to our physical environment, through its tendency
to regard present profits as more important than the future welfare
of mankind.
Bürger:
And socialism?
Storck: Marxist socialism has certainly been a failure, but
it’s important to note that socialism is a slippery term. It was
Pius XI who pointed out that socialism was no longer the monolith
that it had been in Leo XIII’s time. By 1931, when Quadragesimo
Anno appeared, the economic proposals of moderate socialists, as
Pius noted, “at times come very near those that Christian reformers
of society justly insist upon” (no. 113). What makes it impossible
for a Catholic to be a socialist is not necessarily socialist
economic ideas, but the heritage of anti-Christian materialism which
genuine socialist movements carry with them. One can see this in the
fact that European socialist parties, when they come to power,
sometimes are quite willing to make their peace with the existing
capitalist economy, but seldom fail to enact measures attacking the
family, the Church, etc.
Bürger:
What about distributism? It certainly hasn’t been tried on the
level of a nation state, has it? What about local communities,
though?
Storck: As
for distributism, the medieval urban economy, dominated by craft
guilds, was distributist. The guilds attempted to orient economic
activity so that the public received a quality product at a fair
price and individual producers were adequately compensated. As
nation-states and markets grew larger, the distributist order was
bypassed or suppressed in the effort to increase national wealth and
power, but there is no reason why the basic principles of
distributism could not be applied today.
Bürger:
Today, there are many publicly traded companies. Is it wrong to
be able to buy shares of such companies? Isn’t the stock market a
way to distribute ownership?
Storck: The
stock market is not a desirable institution. One can hold shares of
stock without committing a sin (“playing the market” may be
another matter), but that does not mean that the institution is
economically or socially beneficial. It is rather absurd that an
institution that has only an indirect relationship with the real
economy is often considered as a barometer of the health of the
economy. It is always the real economy of production for use that is
important, and the stock market contributes very little toward that.
Rather it can distort the real economy by contributing all sorts of
secondary and even trivial factors that destabilize the functioning
of the economy. When the market crashed in 1929 this was not because
any real economic good, neither farm land, nor factory, had
disappeared or closed. Yet the stock market was eventually able to
bring down the real economy.
Does the stock
market distribute ownership? Not ownership as distributists
understand it! If we keep in mind Pius XI’s definition of
capitalism, the stock marker multiplies capitalist owners, but they
have little or no relationship with the actual product of the company
they own shares in. Sometimes they are hardly aware of what the
company really does, so long as they receive dividend checks or the
price of their stock keeps rising. In fact, stock ownership is the
very type, if you will, of capitalist ownership, stockholders being
people with absolutely no real connection with the firm or its
products. And since shares change hands over and over during a day’s
trading, this diminishes even more the actual connection between
those who are legal owners of the company and the actual company
itself and its products.
Distributism, on the
other hand, tries to promote a real and close relationship between
ownership and work or production. That’s why a very small business
or a worker-owned business is the very type of distributist
ownership.
Bürger:
Distributism came up after Pope Leo XIII published his encyclical
“Rerum novarum,” perhaps the first modern social encyclical. Is
distributism the only possible reading of that document, and
subsequent papal pronouncements on similar questions?
Storck: The
response to Rerum Novarum among Catholics, as well as to the
later social encyclicals, especially Quadragesimo Anno, tended
in two directions. Distributism was more common in English-speaking
countries, while in continental Europe and Latin America a somewhat
different approach predominated, whose best exponent was Fr. Heinrich
Pesch, SJ (d. 1926), author of the magisterial Lehrbuch der
Nationalökonomie and other texts. Pesch, in addition to being a
priest, was an economist trained at the University of Berlin, and
called his system solidarism (Solidarismus). In my
opinion, distributism and solidarism differ more in emphasis than in
substance, with Pesch putting more stress on intermediate groups
(akin to guilds) and labor unions as means for orienting the economy
toward justice and the common good. But each system has important
similarities with the other. Pesch is considered as the main source
for Pius XI’s 1931 encyclical Quadragesimo Anno, and
solidarist ideas lie behind co-determination and other European
efforts to involve workers in management, as Pius XI had recommended
in that encyclical (no. 65), and Leo XIII had suggested even earlier
in Rerum Novarum (nos. 45ff.)
Bürger:
Hilaire Belloc is often described as the founder of distributism. G.
K. Chesterton is one of its main proponents. Neither were trained
economists. Is that problematic?
Storck:
Chesterton and Belloc were both born in the 19th century
when there was still a strong tradition of interest in economic
questions by well-educated intellectuals. Indeed, earlier, Adam Smith
himself was not a trained economist, nor was David Ricardo.
Economics, or the economic welfare of humanity, is important enough
that any intelligent person should take an interest in it. In the
19th century there were numerous schools of economics
which offered greatly varying approaches to the subject, for example
the German Historical School, which eschewed the deductive and
increasingly mathematical approach of the evolving neo-classical
school. Thus both Belloc and Chesterton came out of the tradition of
intelligent non-specialist interest in economic questions which was
characteristic of their times.
Bürger:
There have been many capitalist critics of distributism, for instance
Thomas E. Woods, Jr. Do their critiques have some merit? How would
you answer them?
Storck: I
have argued with the critics of distributism for many years. In many
cases their critique is based on a libertarian view of the economy
and society, which would be as hostile to co-determination, or to any
significant modification of capitalism, as it is to distributism.
In my opinion their
thinking is characterized by a failure to see that the commercial
society which capitalism, whenever it is not severely restrained, has
created and fostered is at odds with the economic maxims of Holy
Scripture and the social teaching of the Church. This is especially
so in the United States, where the kind of capitalism usually
defended is, as I said, closer to the free-market version explicitly
condemned by the Church.
Bürger: Do
you have any book or essay suggestions for our readers?
Storck:
Hilaire Belloc’s, The Restoration of Property is the best
short introduction to distributism by one of its original proponents.
Current distributist writing can be found mostly on two websites, The
Distributist Review, and PracticalDistributism, both of which I write for. Also, the
works of Race Mathews I mentioned earlier, and those of John
Médaille.
Other writers such
as E. F. Schumacher, and Wendell Berry, while perhaps not
distributists in the strict sense, include numerous and important
distributist themes in their writings.
Bürger:
Finally, if you want to bring about a distributist society, what
needs to be done? Which practical suggestions do you have?
Storck: In
the encyclical to which I have referred so often, Quadragesimo
Anno, Pius calls for both a reform of institutions and a reform
of morals. With regard to the first, the law could favor small
enterprises and the formation of micro-businesses and worker-owned
businesses, by giving tax breaks, guaranteed loans, and other
favorable treatment. The law could also discourage concentrations of
property, for instance by impositions of special taxes or enforcement
of anti-trust laws. But at the same time, there would need to come
about a consciousness that the economy does not exist for the sake of
enriching individuals, or even nations, but for providing mankind
with the goods and services needed for a truly human life, while at
the same time allowing us the leisure to give our attention to the
more important things: the things of God, the family, friendships,
the arts and the intellectual life.
In the United
States, which is the place I know best, economic activity is commonly
viewed as a means of getting rich, and the desire to get rich is
considered as an obvious and reasonable aspiration, despite Saint
Paul’s warning (1 Timothy 6:9) that “those who desire to
be rich fall into temptation, into a snare, into many senseless and
harmful desires that plunge people into ruin and destruction.” The
United States is often seen as a very religious, a very Christian
country, but its understanding of Christianity is based on the
Protestant free-church tradition, which tends to privatize religion
and to see it as having little or no connection with the economy or
economic morality. In such a culture it is very difficult for
distributist ideas to make much headway. Hence, when I speak of
measures for creating a climate of opinion favorable to distributism,
what I say may apply more to the United States than to Germany or
other parts of Europe whose cultures were shaped by Catholicism with
its robust concern for the common good of society.
The CNA logo used in the title image of this article is the property of Catholic News Agency.
It is used here to acknowledge them as the source of this article.
It is used here to acknowledge them as the source of this article.
I understood the first paragraph immediately because my husband's family were sharecroppers and rented farms for agriculture.
ReplyDelete